Opinion: Answering farmers’ climate vs. hunger dilemma? It’s textbook.

Back in college, I thought positive economic externalities – i.e., when the benefit of a transaction or economic opportunity spilled over to people not otherwise involved – were mostly confined to graphs in textbooks and the occasional vaccination campaign. Companies, after all, are pretty adept at squeezing all the value they can out of any transaction.

Yet positive externalities exist, and America’s farms are home to the most important example. Farmers will drive two essential efforts in the coming years. First, they must produce enough food to feed 10 billion people by 2050. Second, if they are going to help with climate change mitigation, they will need to lower their greenhouse gas emissions dramatically.

Feeding the world and preventing the planet from burning are quintessential positive externalities. Therefore, we will have to start paying farmers to adopt technologies that can help them do both. It is, quite literally, textbook economics.

Farmers themselves may need to be more comfortable with this. For one thing, Democrats have traditionally supported subsidies for positive externalities, while farmers skew very Republican. According to a Farm Journal poll, 85% of farmers supported President Trump in 2020. Externalities also, by definition, require government intervention, which most farmers do not care for, to put it mildly. They mostly dislike government regulation. Idealized notions of farm life helped build modern conservatism.

Nonetheless, people around the world need farmers to play ball. Agriculture is responsible for 11% of greenhouse gas emissions in the U.S. alone, but currently-available technologies could minimize emissions in the near future. Examples include no-till farming that dramatically reduces fuel use, electric tractors driven by renewable energy, and feed additives that reduce methane emissions from livestock. Widespread use of crushed basalt to sequester carbon on farms could remove as much carbon as taking one car off the road for every man, woman, and child in Omaha, Nebraska.

These techniques and technologies are game-changers, but they’re not cheap. New tractors, electric or otherwise, can cost north of $120,000. Anaerobic digesters, which converts methane-emitting manure into renewable natural gas, can cost over $4 million. When farmers are already dealing with razor-thin profit margins, it’s absurd to expect them to eat costs of this magnitude, even on an amortized basis.

Yet, when farmers adopt these technologies, everyone on the planet benefits. The only reasonable response is to pay farmers to adopt them.

The same is true of maximizing food per acre. That is the only way we will be able to feed 10 billion people; after all, even with just eight billion people, 10% of the world population still goes hungry. As climate change shrinks the world’s arable land and alternative food sources (like fish), meeting the world’s food needs will require we get 70% more food per acre of farmland.

The technology necessary to maximize yield without creating greater emissions already exists. Farmers can leverage big data to pinpoint exactly when to till, plant, water, and harvest. They can use data and predictive analytics to understand exactly how much fertilizer to use. Biological compounds can bind fertilizer to plants, ensuring plants fully benefit from the nutrients and less goes to waste.

These technologies will, if anything, reduce carbon emissions – fertilizer is carbon-intensive to produce (though low-carbon fertilizers do exist). Yet again, they are not cheap. Sophisticated data analytics regimes, for instance, can cost tens of thousands of dollars a year, and are time-consuming to keep up-to-date. Similarly, building climate resilience through initiatives like planting cover crops to protect from extreme heat and using less water is a necessary but expensive defense against catastrophic crop loss.

Of course, many economists argue that climate change is a negative externality and should be addressed by taxing emissions, particularly on farms. Again, that is the textbook “answer.” But it ignores the impact such a tax would have on farms and, by extension, on us. Even in the best-case scenario, such a tax would raise the price of food worldwide, which, as people facing food insecurity from India to Indiana can tell you, would threaten their abilities to make ends meet or even survive. In the worst-case scenario, higher taxes would make many farms financially unsustainable, making it even more difficult to feed 10 billion people by 2050.

Farmers and traditional small-government Republicans may find the idea of paying people to do what is right anathema. Given their opposition, it is incredible that a bill like the Inflation Reduction Act, which makes money available to farmers to pursue emissions-reducing initiatives, could pass at all. And yet, paying farmers is the textbook response to twin existential threats. And textbooks exist for a reason.

Neal Urwitz
Neal Urwitz

Neal Urwitz is a vice president at Antenna Group, a public relations firm working with companies combating the climate crisis.

This article originally appeared on Des Moines Register: Opinion: Farmers' climate vs. hunger dilemma is textbook